Unit 6: Market Failure and the Role of Government

Created
TagsIn Class

6.1 - Socially Efficient and Inefficient Market Outcomes

Definitions

Social Efficiency and the Market Equilibrium

The market equilibrium quantity is equal to the socially optimal quantity only when all social benefits and costs are internalized by individuals in the market.

Total Economic Surplus is maximized at that quantity.

Socially Efficient Point

The Socially Efficient Point occurs when you are producing at the quantity and price level where MSB=MSC\textrm{MSB} = \textrm{MSC}, where all economic surplus is maximized.

If we were to produce either at a quantity above or below the equilibrium, we would be producing at an inefficient point where we are either underproducing or overproducing the good or service. The government sometimes has to take action or make policies to correct these inefficiencies.

Factors that affect Socially Efficient Outcomes

6.2 - Externalities

One of the Ten Principles from Chapter 1: Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity.

In the absence of market failures, the competitive market outcome is efficient and maximizes total surplus. However, there is the possibility for market failures:

One type of market failure is an externality: the uncompensated impact of one person’s actions on the wellbeing of a bystander.

Externalities can be negative or positive, depending on whether impact on bystander is adverse or beneficial.

Self-interested buyers and sellers neglect the external costs or benefit of their actions, so the market outcome is not efficient. In the presence of externalities, government and public policy can often improve outcomes.

Examples of Negative Externalities

Graph of a Negative Externality

When a firm chooses to produce a good or service, it does not take into effect the external costs to society. It just looks at its own production costs. This can create a deadweight loss in the graph, where the social cost exceeds the social benefit. The quantity produced in the free market creates a negative social benefit.

Positive Externalities

In the presence of a positive externality, the social value of a good includes:

The socially optimal QQ maximizes welfare:

You can see in the graph above that at the free market quantity (QFM), marginal social benefit (MSB) is greater than marginal private benefit (MPB). This is marked by point C on the graph above. This essentially means that society is experiencing more benefits than the firm at that quantity. Society would like the firm to produce at point B, which is where marginal social benefit (MSB) equals marginal social cost (MSC). By producing at the free market quantity, a deadweight loss is created. This is marked by the triangle ABC on the graph.

Consumers only consider the marginal private benefit (MPB) of consumption, so consumers will consume until MPB = MSC, and that is where the good will be supplied. To account for the spillover benefits, the government provides a per-unit subsidy to consumers for each unit of the good. When this is done, it makes the good less expensive to buyers which increases the demand for the good. Firms will increase the production of the good to the socially optimal quantity to meet the increased demand.

Internalizing the Externality

Internalizing the Externality: altering incentives so that people take account of the external effects of their actions.

When market participants must pay social costs, the market equilibrium will change to meet the social optimum.

(Imposing the tax on buyers would achieve the same outcome: market QQ would equal optimal QQ).

Effects of Externalities: Summary

If negative externality:

If positive externality:

To remedy the problem:

Public Policies Toward Externalities

Corrective Taxes and Subsidies

Corrective Taxes vs. Regulations

Corrective taxes are better for the environment:

Private Solutions to Externalities

Why Private Solutions Do Not Always Work

6.3 - Public and Private Goods

Public and Common Goods

We consume many goods without paying, such as parks, national defense, clean air and water. When goods have no prices, the market forces that normally allocate resources are absent. Therefore, the private market may fail to provide the socially efficient quantity of these goods.

Important Characteristics of Goods

Different Kinds of Goods

Public Goods

Common Resources

The Tragedy of the Commons

Policy Options to Prevent Overconsumption

Conclusion

6.4 - The Effects of Government Intervention in Different Market Structures

Perfect Competition

In a perfectly competitive market, a tax will shift the supply curve to the left, resulting in a new higher price, a lower quantity demanded, and an associated deadweight loss:

A subsidy in a perfectly competitive market will shift the supply curve to the right, resulting in a new lower price, a higher quantity demanded, and an associated deadweight loss:

Natural Monopoly

A natural monopoly is a market where the most efficient number of firms in the industry is only one. This is often due to high start-up costs. An example of a natural monopoly would be an electric company; it is more efficient for 1 firm to provide power to an entire city rather than having multiple firms with overlapping power grids.

The graph above shows a natural monopoly. Point A is where a monopoly would produce when they are unregulated by the government. Point B represents the fair-return point, where the monopoly would earn a normal economic profit or break even. Point C represents the perfectly competitive or socially optimal point on a monopoly graph. There is no deadweight loss at Point C.

The government can set a price ceiling that can cause a natural monopoly to produce the socially optimal output. The monopoly will need a lump-sum subsidy to produce here.

Per-unit taxes and subsidies affect variable costs, thus affecting the MC\textrm{MC}, ATC\textrm{ATC}, and AVC\textrm{AVC} curves, while lump-sum taxes and subsidies only affect fixed costs, thus affecting only the ATC\textrm{ATC} and AFC\textrm{AFC} curves.

A lump-sum tax will cause an upward shift in the ATC\textrm{ATC} and AFC\textrm{AFC} curves, while a lump-sum subsidy will cause a downward shift in the ATC\textrm{ATC} and AFC\textrm{AFC} curves.

A per-unit tax will cause an upward shift in the ATC\textrm{ATC} and AVC\textrm{AVC} curves, as well as a leftward shift in the MC\textrm{MC} curve. A per-unit subsidy will cause a downward shift in the ATC\textrm{ATC} and AVC\textrm{AVC} curves, as well as a rightward shift in the MC\textrm{MC} curve.

Per-Unit Subsidy - Monopoly
Per-Unit Tax - Monopoly

6.5 - Inequality

There are two types of economic inequality: (1) income inequality, and (2) wealth inequality. Income inequality looks at how annual earnings are distributed and wealth inequality looks at how assets are distributed.

There are several sources of these two types of inequality:

  1. Tax Structure
  1. Human Capital (training and skills)
  1. Social Capital
  1. Inheritance
  1. Effects of Discrimination
  1. Access to Financial Markets
  1. Mobility
  1. Bargaining Power within Economic and Social Units

Income Inequality

Governments use simulation to measure the income inequality level. A graph known as the Lorenz Curve can be used to graphically represent income inequality.

The Lorenz curve shows the actual income distribution in a society. The larger the gap between perfect equality and the Lorenz curve, the greater the amount of income inequality that exists.

The Gini Coefficient is a numerical measurement of income inequality. It is a statistical measurement of income equality where perfect equality is 0 and perfect inequality is 1. The government can help with income inequality by either increasing the amount it taxes wealthier citizens or by increasing transfer payments to the poor. Transfer payments are government payments to individuals or businesses designed to meet a specific objective rather than pay for goods or resources (Ex: welfare).

Types of Taxes

There are several types of taxes that can contribute to or help with income inequality: