Unit 3: Production, Cost, and the Perfect Competition Model

Created
TagsIn Class

3.0 - Overview & Market Structures

Perfect Competition

Monopolistic Competition

Oligopoly

Monopoly

3.1 - The Production Function

Vocabulary

Total, Average, and Marginal Product

Total product (TP)—the total quantity of output produced by a firm in the market.

Average product (AP)—The quantity of total output produced per unit of input used in the production process (Total Product / Units of Inputs).

Marginal product (MP)—The quantity of total output produced by each additional unit of input used in the production process. This is calculated by dividing the change in total product by the change in quantity of input.

The Production Function

The Theory of Production is the idea that input is related to output.

A Production Function shows the relationship between the quantity of inputs used to produce a good and the quantity of output of that good.

The slope of the production function represents the marginal product of labor, the change in output that results from employing an added unit of labor.

MPL=ΔQΔL\textrm {MP}_L = \frac{\Delta Q}{\Delta L}

In continuous terms, the MPL\textrm {MP}_L  is the first derivative of the production function 🤯.

MPL\textrm{MP}_L diminishes as LL increases due to the law of diminishing marginal returns.

Law of Diminishing Marginal Returns

Increasing Marginal Returns—Each additional variable input is more productive than the last. MP and AP increase, as each variable input specializes in its task and utilizes fixed inputs. TP increases at an increasing rate.

Decreasing Marginal Returns—Each additional variable input is less productive than the last. MP and AP decrease as specialization decreases, and there are not enough fixed inputs. TP increases, but at a slower rate.

Negative Marginal Returns—Each additional variable input gets in the way of production. AP decreases and MP becomes negative, as specialization is impossible with too many variable inputs. TP decreases.

The Law of Diminishing Marginal Returns dictates that, as variable resources are added to fixed resources, the additional output produced from each new input will eventually fall. Basically, at some point, each additional worker used in the production process becomes less productive.

Stages of Marginal Returns

Graphs of the Production Function

Table calculating the marginal returns of adding additional workers (inputs).
Total, average, and marginal products depicted on a graph.

Relating Total, Average, and Marginal Products

Relationship between Marginal Product and Total Product

The law of variable proportions explains the relationship between Total Product and Marginal Product. It states that when only one variable factor input is allowed to increase and all other inputs are kept constant, the following can be observed:

Relationship between Average Product and Marginal Product

There exists an interesting relationship between Average Product and Marginal Product:

3.2 - Short-Run Production Costs

In the short-run, at least 1 resource is fixed, or cannot change. Fixed resources can include plant capacity, or the number of factories in operation.

Fixed, Variable, and Total Costs

Fixed Cost (FC)—The costs of fixed resources used during the production process. These costs do not change with the amount of output produced. Ex: rent, salaries, insurance.

Variable Cost (VC)—The costs of variable resources used during the production process. These costs do change with the amount of output produced. The more output produced, the higher the variable costs are and vice versa. Ex: electricity, hourly wages, shipping costs.

Total Cost (TC)—The sum of variable costs and fixed costs.

Marginal Cost (MC)—The additional cost of producing each additional unit of output. (MC=ΔTCΔQ\textrm{MC} = \frac{\Delta TC}{\Delta Q})

  • Profit is maximized when MC=MR\textrm{MC} = \textrm{MR}, so you will continue to produce more output until these two quantities are equal.

Relating Fixed, Variable, and Total Costs

Fixed Costs+Variable Costs=Total Costs\textrm{Fixed Costs} + \textrm{Variable Costs} = \textrm{Total Costs}

Average Costs

Average Fixed Cost (AFC)—Fixed cost divided by the quantity of output

Average Variable Cost (AVC)—Variable cost divided by the quantity of output.

Average Total Cost (ATC)—Total cost divided by the quantity of output.

Average Fixed Costs+Average Variable Costs=Average Total Costs\textrm{Average Fixed Costs} + \textrm{Average Variable Costs} = \textrm{Average Total Costs}

Economic Profit vs. Accounting Profit

Implicit cost—Opportunity costs associated with decisions in the production of goods and services. Ex: If an individual gives up an annual salary to open a business, then that salary is seen as an implicit cost.

Accounting costs—The explicit or "out of pocket" payments paid by firms to use resources during the production process.

Economic costs—The sum of both the implicit costs (opportunity costs) and explicit costs of production. These costs include both the "out of pocket" payments paid by firms and the opportunity costs of using resources during the production process.

Accounting profits—The profits earned by the firm when the revenue earned by the firm is greater than the explicit (accounting) costs of production (Total Revenue - Accounting Costs).

Economic profits—The profits earned by the firm when the revenue earned by the firm is greater than the sum of the explicit (accounting) costs and the implicit (opportunity cost) costs of production (Total Revenue - Economic Costs).

Accounting profits ignore the implicit costs, and therefore will always appear higher than economic profit.

Graphical Depictions of Fixed, Variable, and Total Cost

Example table of a firm's FC, VC, and TC, and how those are related to the firm's output.

What FC, VC, and TC look like on a graph. Notice the fixed costs just move the graph of VC upwards to reach TC.
Graph of marginal cost (MC), average fixed cost (AFC), average variable cost (AVC), and average total cost (ATC).

MC always crosses both AVC and ATC at their lowest point. If fixed costs increase, then both the AFC and ATC would shift up and vice versa. If variable costs increase, then both AVC and ATC will shift upward and vice versa. The MC curve only shifts when variable costs change. It will shift upward for an increase in variable costs and downward for a decrease in variable costs.

Graphs shifting upward with a change in variable cost.

3.3 - Long-Run Production Costs

In the long-run, all resources are flexible, so firms can change both their plant capacity and output level. This allows firms to analyze and compare the average total cost of production at each plant capacity in the short-run, and find the optimal plant capacity that allows them to product output at the lowest possible ATC.

This the LRATC curve is merely the combination of several SRATC curves for different facilities.

The U-shape of the long-run ATC (LRATC) curve is a result of economies of scale and diseconomies of scale that are experienced by the firm.

The light blue area represents economies of scale because as output is increasing, costs are decreasing. The light yellow area represents a constant return to scales because as output continues to increase, costs remain constant. The light green area represents diseconomies of scale because as output increases, costs rise.

3.4 - Types of Profit

In economics, there are a variety of different ways to represent profits. These different methods of calculating profits vary based on what type of costs are being considered in each situation. Profit, in general, is the difference between total revenue and total costs (provided total revenue is greater than total costs).

If revenue is less than costs, a firm may experience economic losses. For example, if the total revenue is $80 and the total cost is $97, we have an economic loss of $17.

When a firm is experiencing an economic profit, they can increase their production. If a firm is earning an economic loss, they will most likely respond by decreasing their output.

3.5 - Profit Maximization

MR=MC\textrm{MR} = \textrm{MC}

At the point where MR\textrm{MR} equals MC\textrm{MC}, the costs of producing the last unit of output equals the revenue gained when selling it. At this point, a firm's profit is maximized.

For a firm in perfect competition, MR=P\textrm{MR} = \textrm P.

Revenue and Costs for an Example Firm

Using this example firm's revenue and costs, we can see that the profit-maximizing quantity is 3 units, where both the marginal revenue and marginal cost equal $7.

MC and the Firm's Supply Decision

If the price of a good increases from P1P_1 to P2P_2, then the profit maximizing quantity rises to Q2Q_2. The MC\textrm{MC} curve determines the firm's QQ at any price. (Provided the firm is in perfect competition, as the market sets the price).

3.6 - Firms' Short-Run Decisions to Produce and Long-Run Decisions to Enter or Exit a Market

Shut-Down Rule

A shutdown is a short-run decision not to produce anything because of market conditions. The shutdown rule states that a firm should continue to produce and operate so long as price is equal to or above the firm's AVC.

Because on the graph above, the profit maximizing quantity (where MR=MC\textrm{MR} = \textrm{MC}) is below the AVC\textrm{AVC} curve, the firm should choose to shutdown and not produce. If the profit maximizing quantity is anywhere above the AVC\textrm{AVC} curve, the firm should produce.

The Irrelevance of Sunk Costs

A sunk cost is a cost that has already been committed and cannot be recovered.

Sunk costs are irrelevant to the shutdown decision, as you have to pay them regardless of your choice. FC\textrm{FC} is a sunk cost, as the firm must pay these costs regardless of if they choose to shut down or not. Therefore, FC\textrm{FC} should not be factored in to the decision to shutdown.

Long-Run Decisions to Enter or Exit the Market

Long-Run Decision to Exit

Long-Run Decision to Enter

3.7 - Perfect Competition

Characteristics of Perfect Competition

Assumptions in Market Supply

  1. All exisiting firms and potential entrands have identical costs.
  1. Each firm's costs do not change as other firms enter or exit the market.
  1. The number of firms in the market is:
    1. Fixed in the short run
    1. Variable in the long run

Side-by-Side Graphs of Perfect Competiton

Since firms are price-takers in perfect completion, a firm's MC and MR graph is directly related to the market supply and demand graph. The part of the MC curve that is above the MR curve is the same as the firm's supply curve.

In a perfectly competitive market in the short-run, a graph can display three possible scenarios. They can show a short-run profit, short-run loss, or short-run shutdown.

Short-Run Profit

When a firm is making a short-run profit, its profit per unit = PATC\textrm P - \textrm{ATC}. Therefore, the firm's total profit is equal to (PATC)×Q(\textrm P - \textrm{ATC}) \times Q.

Short-Run Loss

A short-run loss is shown when the ATC is located above the price line at the profit-maximizing point, and the AVC curve is located below the price line at the profit-maximizing point.

When a firm is making short-run losses, its loss per unit equals ATCP\textrm{ATC} - \textrm P. Therefore, the firm's total loss is equal to (ATCP)×Q(\textrm{ATC} - \textrm P) \times Q.

Short-Run Shutdown

A business will shutdown when both ATC and AVC are located above the price line at the profit-maximizing point, as shown above.

Long-Run Perfectly Competitive Graph

When a perfectly competitive market is in long-run equilibrium, we show this on the side by side graphs by having ATC tangent to the price line at the profit-maximizing quantity (MR = MC). When a perfectly competitive market is in long-run equilibrium, it is both allocatively efficient and productively efficient. On a graph, allocative efficiency is P(MR) = MC, and productive efficiency is P = minimum ATC.

Shift from Short-Run to Long-Run Equilibrium in a Perfectly Competitive Market

When a short-run perfectly competitive market is earning either a profit or loss, firms will want to either enter or exit the market, thus market shifting the market from short-run to long-run.

When a firm is earning a profit, this provides an incentive for firms not already in the industry to enter because of the possible profit. This will cause the supply curve to shift right due to the increase in supply, which will lower the market price and in turn lower the price for each firm.

This can be illustrated on a graph by shifting the price line down to become tangent with ATC. The profit-maximizing quantity for the firm will decrease. The market quantity will increase as there are now more firms in the industry, but each individual firm is supplying less of that overall quantity.

The below graphs show how a perfectly competitive market goes from a short-run profit to long-run equilibrium.

Since firms joining the market reduces the profit made by each firm, eventually some firms will be incentivized to leave the market, repeating in a cycle until the remaining firms earn zero profit:

The Zero-Profit Condition

Why do firms say in business with zero profits? Recall that economic profit is revenue minus all costs, including implicit costs like the opportunity cost of the owner's time and money. In zero-profit equilibrium, firms earn enough revenue to cover these costs. Thus, accounting profit is still positive, and firms still have a strong incentive to produce.

Shift from Long-Run to Short-Run back to Long-Run

A market may be in long-run equilibrium, and then experience a change in demand in the market. This shift of demand moves the market into short-run, and then it has to readjust back to long-run.

Let's show how this occurs when there is a scenario that increases demand. We'll use the market for apples.

Step 1

A market is in long-run equilibrium, when a change in market demand causes the price of the good to increase. We show this on the firm graph by shifting the price line up and identifying the new profit-maximizing point for the firm (MR=MC\textrm{MR} = \textrm{MC}). This causes the firm to go from long-run equilibrium to short-run profit since the price line is above the ATC curve.

Step 2

Now that the perfectly competitive market is earning a short-run profit, individual firms are incentivized to enter the market. This makes the supply curve shift right, causing the equilibrium price to decrease. This will cause the price line to drop on the firm graph and cause the profit-maximizing quantity to return to the original one in the firm.

This can happen anytime a perfectly competitive market starts in long-run equilibrium and gets moved to short-run. The market always has to readjust to long-run equilibrium.

Changes Due to the Assumptions of the Perfect Competition Model

  1. Firms have different costs
    • A PP rises, firms with lower costs enter the market before those with higher costs.
    • Further increases in PP make it worthwhile for higher-cost firms to enter the market, which increases market quantity supplied.
    • Hence, the LR\textrm{LR} market supply curve slopes upward.
    • At any PP,
      • For the marginal firm, P=minimum ATCP = \textrm{minimum ATC} and profit=0\textrm{profit} = 0.
      • For lower-cost firms, profit>0\textrm{profit} > 0.
  1. Costs Rise as Firms Enter the Market
    • In some industries, the supply of a key input is limited.
    • The entry of new firms increases demand for this input, causing its price to rise.
    • This increases all firms' costs.
    • Hence, an increase in PP is required to increase the market quantity supplied, so the supply curve is upward-sloping.

Conclusion: The Efficiency of a Competitive Market